Biden’s Minimum Wage

Patrick Watson | Connecting the Dots
January 19, 2021

Last week President-Elect Joe Biden revealed a pandemic relief proposal. The list was mostly predictable: direct cash payments, enhanced unemployment benefits, vaccine funding, help for state and local governments.

But Biden’s wish list had one item I didn’t expect: raising the federal minimum wage to $15 an hour.

Labor advocates have been asking for this for years, and it’s no surprise a Democratic administration would try. But the idea isn’t directly pandemic-related. There’s some connection: The virus has spread partly because so many low-wage workers have had to keep working in high-contact environments. Raising the minimum wage won’t immediately fix that problem. So why connect them?

Maybe it’s a bargaining chip. Even if Congress rejects that part, Biden may get something else in exchange, and would also have publicized an idea he can raise again later.

But so far, at least, there hasn’t been much objection. Republicans seem more determined to stop the state and local aid. So a $15 national minimum wage might actually pass soon.

And if it does, the economic consequences could be important.


Photo: Wikimedia Commons

Price Control

Minimum wage laws are a form of price control. They override market forces and tell employers, “You can buy labor only if you pay this much.” Likewise, minimum wage laws tell workers, “You may only sell your labor if you charge this much.”

In much of the US, prevailing wages are already well above the statutory minimum, which is $7.25/hour federally and more in some states and cities.

This patchwork created a kind of laboratory to measure the effect. In theory, unemployment should be higher in places with a higher minimum wage. Sometimes it is, but not always.

Filtering out other effects is hard when businesses can cut labor costs by moving outside the city limits or across a state line. Customers can easily follow.

A $15 federal minimum, applicable to the whole country, would clarify this—and have other effects, too.


Source: Wikimedia Commons

Productivity Gain

In proposing the $15 minimum wage, Biden said, “No one working 40 hours a week should live below the poverty line.”

That’s a moral statement, not an economic one, but codifying morality into law is what governments do. We elect Congress and the president to find the right balance.

Evidence suggests that most people agree with Biden on this—even the Republican base. Florida just voted in November to gradually raise its minimum wage to $15 by 2026, on the same ballot that gave Donald Trump Florida’s electoral votes. So a national minimum wage hike looks politically feasible.

One result might be higher prices for labor-intensive goods and services. But that assumes productivity stays the same. It may not. Workers who don’t have to wonder if they can afford their next meal ought to be happier and more productive.

But there would be some effect, and not just for the lowest-tier workers.

Say a company’s junior workers make $10 or $12 per hour, and more experienced ones presently make $15. If the minimum goes up to $15, those in the lower tier will get a raise… but those already making $15 or more will probably get a raise, too, reflecting their higher relative value. And those above them, and up the chain.

A higher minimum wage, depending on the details and how it is phased in, might raise wages well up the pay scale. And that’s where the macro effects get interesting.


Source: Wikimedia Commons

Macro Effects

One mystery of recent years is why the so-called “Phillips Curve” stopped working. That’s an old economic theory that inflation and unemployment are inversely related. We have instead seen low unemployment and low inflation, until the pandemic struck.

(You can argue, as I did here and here, that inflation really wasn’t so low for most people. But set that aside for now.)

Seemingly low inflation encouraged the Federal Reserve to keep interest rates artificially low since 2008. Now they’re even lower, thanks to pandemic monetary stimulus. Fed officials have repeatedly said they won’t tighten rates until they see significant, persistent inflation.

A higher minimum wage may generate, or at least aggravate, the conditions that will force the Fed to tighten rates. That would have serious effects on asset prices, the government’s financing costs, and the housing market.

These effects aren’t necessarily bad. But they would be noticeable.

A lot depends on where the money comes from. We’ll get inflation if the higher wages push prices higher. But that’s not inevitable. Competition might force businesses to accept lower profit margins.

In that case, the bigger consequence might be distributional. Money that wealthy business executives and shareholders would once have saved will instead go to low-wage workers, who will spend it.

You’ve heard of “income inequality.” Even many conservatives agree it is a problem for a small number of wealthy investors to earn so much, while many workers earn so little.

A government policy that forces wages higher will transfer income from capital to labor. Exactly what the results would be are hard to say at this point. But it looks like we may find out.

See you at the top,

Patrick Watson
@PatrickW

Scroll down for comments.

Disqus Comments
View More Articles